July 28, 2022

Reviews

The Last Days of Sound Finance

On Karen Petrou’s “Engine of Inequality”

Engine of Inequality: The Fed and the Future of Wealth in America
By Karen Petrou
Wiley, 2021

When the Federal Reserve turned to unconventional monetary policy in 2008, many feared that we would soon see a return to the wage-price spiral of the 1970s. The combination of deficit spending and monetary ease raised the old specter of debt monetization, in which the Treasury sells its debt directly to the central bank instead of the bond market, thereby freeing itself from interest obligations and market discipline. (Pejoratively, this is referred to as “printing money.”) But while quantitative easing (QE) did involve the mass purchase of Treasury bonds by the Federal Reserve, the Fed was buying these bonds from private financial institutions, not from the Treasury itself. Instead of opening a direct line from the central bank to the Treasury (a public—and, in theory, democratic—entity) , the Fed’s “money printing” operation detoured around the Treasury to create new reserves on the books of primary-dealer banks.      

This was, at best, an indirect form of debt monetization. But inflation hawks nevertheless turned to the well-worn scripts of the 1970s to make sense of what was happening. By driving down interest rates on future government borrowing, they warned, QE would encourage wanton social spending and release workers from the discipline of the market. Wages would inevitably be driven upwards at the expense of profits.1 They need not have worried. Beginning with the Troubled Asset Relief Program or TARP, which bailed out private financial institutions while leaving indebted households underwater, post-crisis fiscal stimulus has prevented a collapse in consumption but done little to offset the astounding concentration of wealth and income at the top.2 For all these reasons and more, the Fed’s decade-long (and counting) experiment with the money printer has failed to resurrect the wage-push consumer-price inflation of the early 1970s.3

When advocates of economic expansion proclaim that “this is not a return of the 1970s,” it is meant to be reassuring. But should it be? Arguably, the late 1960s and early 1970s represented the most effective challenge to wealth concentration in the long twentieth century and the closest the United States has ever come to fiscal revolution.4 By contrast, unconventional monetary policy, even when it has lowered unemployment, has only intensified inequality. Instead of wage inflation, we got asset-price inflation and, following the worldwide supply shocks of the coronavirus pandemic, stand-alone consumer price inflation. Not downward but vertiginous upward redistribution. Economic historians have commonly argued that pandemics, wars, and other exogenous shocks tend to empower labor and compress income disparities.5 This prognosis was not borne out during the coronavirus crisis, when central banks around the world reprised their large-scale asset purchases and predictably drove asset prices to new heights. Between the first quarter of 2020 and the second quarter of 2021, the top 1 percent of US income earners averaged net-wealth gains of $3.5 million per person, compared to $5,300 among the bottom 50 percent.6 The picture is even more disturbing when we consider that one in five Americans is a lifetime renter. With the end of coronavirus moratoriums, the rapid inflation of property prices has left millions of households (disproportionately minority and female-led) faced with escalating rents and eviction.7 Just when catastrophic weather events are becoming a fact of life, basic shelter has turned into a luxury good. 

The last three chairs of the US Federal Reserve have been loath to acknowledge any link between unconventional monetary policy and soaring inequality. Other central bank officials have been surprisingly forthcoming. In 2012, an anonymous report in the Bank of England’s quarterly bulletin admitted that rising asset prices had overwhelmingly benefited the top 5 percent of households due to their disproportionate share of financial assets such as stocks and bonds in their wealth portfolios.8 Although more evasive on the question of their own responsibility, both the Bank’s former Governor Mark Carney and former Chief Economist Andrew Haldane have recognized the role played by QE in exacerbating extreme wealth concentration.9 Others—including in-house economists at the Federal Reserve and Bank for International Settlements—have added their voice to the chorus, while in the meantime a handful of academic economists have undertaken the slow work of demonstrating the causal connections between ultra-low interest rates, central bank asset purchases, and the swollen asset portfolios of the wealthiest households.10

Asset-price strategy

Taken as a whole, this literature is damning in its assessment of institutional failure on the part of central banks and fiscal authorities. Yet for the most part, it lacks the panoramic scope that would propel it forcefully onto the public agenda. Karen Petrou’s Engine of Inequality is the first monograph to systematically investigate the distributive impact of the Federal Reserve’s unconventional monetary policy and to do so with the explicit aim of advancing alternatives. Although closely engaged with a dauntingly technical literature, the book is eminently accessible to a wider reading public. This makes for an enormously important contribution to the debate on wealth concentration and its institutional drivers.

Petrou aptly describes the Fed’s large-scale asset purchases and ultra-low interest rates as a kind of “trickle down” monetary policy. In theory, lowering the price of money is intended to encourage banks to step up their lending to households and businesses, whose higher risk profile would otherwise have deprived them of access to credit. In turn, this new lending would enable an expansion of personal consumption and business investment, both of which would generate new employment across the economy. Things did not turn out as planned, however. Instead of channeling liquidity downwards, banks have proven highly reluctant to lend to low- and moderate-income households. Credit flows to the business and corporate sector have privileged financial investments like share buybacks and private equity deals, whose main purpose is to bid up stock prices. If this is “supply side” policy, it is only in the sense that it has expanded the supply of credit in the service of asset price appreciation. There has been very little increase in the kind of long-range capital investment that would favor high-wage employment or empower workers. While the downward trickle failed to materialize, high-end portfolios have continued to appreciate. As a loose supply of credit bids up the price of financial assets, the benefits flow to those who hold relatively more of their wealth in the form of stocks, private equity, and the like.

Where some see unintended consequences, Petrou reminds us that raising asset prices was the Fed’s explicit goal. Four years into QE, Ben Bernanke still counted on “declining yields and rising asset prices” to “ease overall financial conditions and stimulate economic activity” across the board.11 Petrou rightly traces this doctrine back to former Federal Reserve chairman Alan Greenspan, who from the mid-1990s to 2006 presided over a historic boom in asset prices. The foundation of the boom was the so-called “Greenspan put,” an implicit guarantee that the Federal Reserve would protect asset markets from downside risk, thereby assuring wealth holders that their portfolios would appreciate. Though he shared the central banker’s traditional hostility to wage inflation, Greenspan saw asset-price inflation as benign.14 Greenspan sat back and let “worker insecurity” do the rest. Labor figured in his political calculus only to the extent that workers might also become asset owners. If everyone could own (or aspire to own) a home, workers would be less inclined to fight back against stagnant wages.  

This democratic twist on the asset-price strategy—always problematic—is no longer on the table. Homeownership rates fell by more than 5 percent following the subprime crisis of 2007 and house prices are now out of reach for middle-income earners in many major cities. As Petrou demonstrates, low-cost bank credit has become even less accessible to so-called “subprime” households, despite the trillions of QE intended to stimulate such lending. Even with historically low interest rates, the income- and asset-poor have become ever more dependent on credit cards and extortionate payday loans.

A limited toolbox?

Petrou is illuminating on the distributional impacts of unconventional monetary policy. Her proposals for exiting the impasse, however, are less convincing. She argues that we need to act hard and fast to halt the momentum of asset-price inflation, insisting that the only tool we can count on is monetary policy. If the Fed created this mess in the first place, then only the Fed can get us out of here. Thus, she sees the unloading of the Federal Reserve’s bloated balance sheet along with a steady rise in interest rates as the best medicine for the job. By contrast, she flatly dismisses fiscal solutions including a wealth tax, an increase in federal spending on education and social welfare, or a federal infrastructure program. For Petrou, all such interventions are futile given the longueurs of the budgetary process and the inertia of the existing system of government transfers.      

Given the crushing disappointment of Biden’s first year in office, it is easy to see why pragmatically minded reformers might want to abandon the fiscal toolbox altogether. We live in a time where even the most conservative Keynesian maneuvers look wildly utopian. So, realists retreat to the technical fixes of central bank monetary policy as the easiest way out. Petrou’s failure to envisage a more ambitious public-spending agenda is motivated by more than pragmatism, however. At one point, she rejects any “overtly redistributive proposal” for equalizing wealth on the grounds that it “would hurt what’s left of the US middle class.” Elsewhere, she resurrects the classic “crowding out” thesis, once beloved by fiscal conservatives. In a curious inversion of the formula that once saw government deficit spending as crowding out private investment, Petrou contends that “increased federal deficits [have] destroyed public wealth” (emphasis added). Supposedly, “the more the deficit grows, the less net wealth US taxpayers collectively own and thus the less there is not only to go around, but also to devote to progressive policies.”  The logic is unclear, even incoherent: why can’t deficit-financed public investment increase public “wealth”? Moreover, accounting principles mean that a government deficit must correspond to a surplus on some private balance sheet—the opposite of the negative-sum conflict imagined here. Petrou seems unaware or unconcerned that recent experience (ten years of post-financial crisis deficit spending, followed by lavish if temporary public spending during the coronavirus crisis) has powerfully refuted old orthodoxies.

If Petrou’s implied point is that elite reactions to deficit-spending will vary depending on how (and for whom) money is being spent, she is right. Budget constraints reflect the struggle for power, not the implacable force of supposed economic laws. But Petrou seems genuinely, even quaintly, devoted to financial conventions that few others are following. Like Bill Clinton, who cast the New Democrats as Eisenhower Republicans fighting the excesses of Reagan Republicans, Petrou is a center-leftist stubbornly attached to yesterday’s conservatism. Having outlined QE’s outrageous transgressions of the rules of sound finance and its contributions to inequality, she shows little appetite for breaking those same rules on behalf of redistribution. She rejects not only Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), which sanctions permanent debt monetization, but even “helicopter money,” the more limited form of emergency central bank money creation advocated by Milton Friedman and (at one point) Ben Bernanke.  

This leaves Petrou with a slim set of monetary and regulatory options to choose from. Ultimately, she looks to monetary tightening and fiscal restraint to rein in asset prices and replenish the savings accounts of a rapidly receding “middle class.” Yet she does not explain how low- and middle-income households—already “struggling to manage day-to-day consumption”—can simultaneously maintain their living standards, increase their savings rate, lose access to consumer credit, and face higher interest charges on existing debt. The fact is that monetary policy alone is impotent to address the gross inequities of our time unless the fiscal levers of spending and taxation are also put into play. As Gerald Epstein and Juan Montecino remark, the paradox of our current conjuncture is that “both loose and tight monetary policy are likely to be disequalizing.”15 Given this dilemma, a lack of “utopian” vision turns out to be a practical liability. Absent a more imaginative fiscal politics, Petrou can only offer up a progressive version of sound finance. 

Abandoning “shared growth”

Petrou’s call for tighter monetary policy has now been answered by Jerome Powell’s Federal Reserve, which in July 2022 hiked interest rates by three quarters of a point, the highest percentage in decades, for the second month in a row. This policy turn represents a fatal misreading of the economic landscape. The current run up in consumer prices is driven by the supply-chain bottlenecks of the coronavirus pandemic, the Russian invasion of Ukraine, and profit-push price hikes on the part of business—not a return to the wage-price spiral of the 1970s.16 A rise in interest rates will do nothing to resolve these supply-chain issues and will certainly not help low-income workers, the unemployed, or the chronically indebted. 

The Fed’s conviction that low-wage workers must be punished for over-exuberant demand is grotesque. But it is internally coherent. Powell acknowledges that the point of tight money is to reduce business investment and “temper growth.” This economic slowdown will ensure that supposed “wage pressures move back down,” rectifying the “real imbalance in wage negotiating” which Powell now sees as a dangerous consequence of easy money. Contrast this with Petrou, who claims that tighter money will increase investment and employment: “The lower these [rates] go, the less companies spend on investment, the harder it is for lower-skilled workers to find jobs.” She acknowledges that investment is led by demand (“The less the nation spends for overall consumption of goods and services, the less need for businesses to invest in new plants and infrastructure to meet demand”) but believes that somehow tighter money will mean more demand. These tortured constructs reflect a stubborn refusal to accept what Powell freely admits: monetary policy simply cannot reverse hyper-wealth concentration nor revive what Petrou calls “shared growth.” 

It is worth remembering the actual historical contours of “shared growth.” The last time we saw any significant compression of wealth and income inequality was in the postwar era, when federal and state governments poured money into public construction projects and lavishly subsidized the “private” manufacturing sector. Vigorous growth rates meant that wages could rise without threatening the profit share of national income. This is how the limited Keynesianism of the New Deal state was supposed to work. The period after 1965 saw a significant expansion of social and redistributive public spending relative to defense outlays and an upsurge in labor militancy across the private and public sector. When wages kept rising, even as industrial profits came under threat from foreign competition and rising oil prices, industrial employers and financial asset holders alike quickly lost interest in maintaining the Keynesian peace. No longer a respected partner, unionized labor had revealed itself as an enemy of the free-enterprise system and, via “wage-push inflation,” the prime cause of the nation’s economic ills. 

Wage-push inflation could just as well have been dubbed profit-push inflation, since the rise in consumer prices reflected an ongoing struggle between workers and business owners rather than the outright victory of labor unions. Yet the fact that the distribution of income could shift, even momentarily, in favor of workers was enough to dissolve any commitment on the part of business to shared growth. (In 1974, a young Alan Greenspan told a group of social-service bureaucrats that Wall Street stockbrokers were harder hit “percentage wise” by inflation than the poor—an undiplomatic statement that revealed what it really meant to “whip” inflation).17

Monetary policy and the fiscal state

The long counter-revolution of the last half-century—which has seen central banks relentlessly attack the slightest sign of wage growth while doing all in their power to promote the inflation of asset prices—would not have surprised Michał Kalecki. In a famous 1943 essay, the Polish economist predicted that sustained efforts by government to subsidize public services, welfare, and wages would at some point release workers from the fear of unemployment and therefore generate a powerful backlash coalition of industrialists and rentiers.18 More than merely diagnosing the dilemmas of full employment, Kalecki’s prescient essay also suggests that the path to revolution might pass through and beyond the fiscal state. When social spending and redistribution is pushed too far, industrialists and wealth holders unite in opposition. But what would it mean to deliberately push Keynesianism beyond these limits—as well as beyond the familial, racial, national, and class-based limits within which the welfare state has historically been confined? Put differently, is it even possible to entertain the prospect of communism today without some sense of how to collectivize the process of money and debt creation? 

Contemporary Marxists have neglected these possibilities. Too often, they invoke a strangely philological understanding of revolution, one attuned to an era before the fiscal state and modern central bank, in which workers merely had to take over the means of production while militants seized the executive powers of the state.19 But any radical challenge to capitalism today would also need to seize the means of money creation, collective spending, and taxation. When Marxist economists dismiss MMT as a Keynesian half-measure, they are stating the obvious. There is real value in MMT’s claim that fiscal and monetary actions should be judged by their real-world effects rather than their distance from supposed economic laws. But in other respects, it remains committed to the Keynesian project of dialectical mediation, with all its built-in buffers—the distinction between productive and unproductive labor, the confinement of social democracy within national borders, and the fear of excessive wage growth.20 That this is a limited project goes without saying. The whole point of Keynesianism is to moderate the relationship between labor and capital, so that central bank money creation and the state’s power to tax and spend never lead to the full-blown socialization of finance. It is easy to see why Petrou—a social liberal with distinctly unambitious fiscal politics—would shun MMT’s promise to dissolve financial constraints. But for Marxists, time spent rehearsing old critiques of reformism is time away from more urgent tasks. Until we develop our own politics of collective finance, the left will face an unsatisfying choice between celebrating QE or defaulting to a hawkishness that is ultimately hard to distinguish from sound-money nostalgia.21

So far, the most creative proposals have come from activist groups like Strike Debt! or the more advocacy-focused New Economics Foundation and Positive Money. Each of these have drawn on the full range of monetary and fiscal alternatives to advocate for a more redistributive economic policy. Although hardly exceptional by the historical standards of Keynesian (or even monetarist) thinking, their demands—for a more expansive social-spending agenda, mass debt forgiveness, or a “Quantitative Easing for the People”—hold far more promise than the return to sound finance promoted by centrists like Petrou as well as the occasional Marxist. 

If skeptics are right about one thing,  it is that such experiments will never be implemented at scale without a fight. Macroeconomic policy is not, and should not, be an exclusively technocratic or parliamentary affair. The fiscal state is just as capable as the factory floor of inciting transformative conflicts. The decade-long upsurge in public-sector militancy is one instance of a labor struggle that directly touches the levers of public finance, and therefore represents a crucial site of fiscal intervention.22 Public-sector unionism is sometimes dismissed as peripheral to the real work of anti-capitalist struggle on the grounds that the fulcrum of capitalist power relations lies in the profit-making private sector. This anachronistic assumption misreads the last century of economic organization, which saw “private sector” surplus-value production massively underwritten by the state, whether through direct subventions, tax expenditures or government contracts, and thereby misses the hidden affinities between public- and private-sector unionism. It also overlooks the genuine fear that public-sector workers are capable of inspiring among political elites, as when Fed chair Arthur Burns described the 1970 postal wildcat strike as “an insurrection against the Government.”23

The relative importance of public-sector unions in today’s labor movement should not be lamented. As a movement that includes large numbers of women and minority workers, public-sector organizing has the potential to transcend the gender- and race-based trade-offs of earlier worker insurgencies. The sector’s visible dependence on government support—historically seen as a vulnerability—also offers unique opportunities. Public-sector movements are forced to dredge up problems which are usually submerged: the relationship between labor income, asset prices, and government spending; the distributional stakes of taxation and credit creation; the contradictory imperatives of reproducing an increasingly unequal society. That public-sector challenges can become sources of strength is demonstrated by initiatives such as the Bargaining for the Common Good Network, which builds coalitions between striking public-sector workers and their “clients” (students, parents, patients, commuters, etc.) while also coordinating campaigns that join the dots between government budgeting and everyday austerity. To get a sense of how far reaching such campaigns can be, the United Teachers Los Angeles (UTLA) has fought to lift the commercial property-tax limit on school funding; turn school-owned vacant land into affordable housing; and contain the power of the private equity funds which exploit renters (through their real-estate portfolios) as well as teachers (through state tax policies that privilege capital gains at the expense of funding for schools).24 This is a model for unionists public and private. More than that, it represents one way in which the reins of fiscal and monetary power might be seized from below. 

  1. Richard W. Fisher, President, “Recent Decisions of the Federal Open Market Committee: A Bridge to Fiscal Sanity? (Acknowledging Henry B. Gonzalez and Winston Churchill): Remarks before the Association for Financial Professionals,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, November 8 (2010).

  2. See on this site, Ho-fung Hung’s analysis of the impact of coronavirus stimulus spending on Amazon profits and wages, respectively. Ho-fung Hung, “Repressing Labor, Empowering China,” Phenomenal World July 2 (2021). Ho-fung Hung advances a “labor theory of inflation” germane to the one I am suggesting here to explain why we have not seen any significant increase in wages despite massive government spending during the coronavirus pandemic.

  3. Although the wage-profit-consumer price spiral of the early 1970s was real enough, Federal Reserve economists have found little evidence that debt monetization was in play even then. Daniel L. Thornton, “Monetizing the Debt,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (1984): 30-43.

  4. In the United States, Edward Wolff reports a fairly steady decline in wealth concentration between the early 1920s and the mid 1970s. The share of total wealth held by the top 1 percent reached its lowest point in the early 1970s. Wealth inequality began to rise again from the mid-1970s. Edward N. Wolff, A Century of Wealth in America (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 2017), 148-54. For comparable results, see Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2017), 291-94. On the relative insulation of unionized workers and welfare recipients from the effects of 1970s’ consumer price inflation, thanks to built-in cost of living adjustments, see Edward N. Wolff, “The Distributional Effects of the 1969–75 Inflation on the Holdings of Household Wealth in the United States,” Review of Income and Wealth 25, no. 2 (1979), 21-43, Joseph J. Minarik, “The Distributional Effects of Inflation and Their Implications,” in Stagflation: The Causes, Effects and Solutions (Washington, DC: Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, 1980), 225–77, and Douglas A. Hibbs, Jr. The American Political Economy: Macroeconomics and Electoral Politics (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1987), 90-92. Wolff, who conducted a study investigating the effects of inflation on household wealth between 1969 and 1974, went so far as to argue that inflation “acted like a progressive tax, leading to greater equality in the distribution of wealth” (207).

  5. The argument rests on the morbid yet optimistic assumption that mass death will create labor shortages and thus empower the surviving workers. Recent proponents of this argument are Walter Scheidel, The Great  The argument rests on the morbid yet optimistic assumption that mass death will create labor shortages and thus empower the surviving workers. Recent proponents of this argument are Walter Scheidel, The Great Leveler:Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2018) and Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2017).

  6. UN DESA, The Monetary Policy Response to COVID-19: The Role of Asset Purchase Programmes: Policy Brief No. 129 (New York: United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, 2021), 5.

  7. See Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, Housing insecurity and the COVID-19 Pandemic (Washington, DC: CFPB, 2021), and Faith Weekly, “Addressing the Housing Affordability Crisis as COVID-19’s Impact Continues,” Federal Reserve Bank of St-Louis February 24 (2022)

  8. Anonymous, “The Distributional Effects of Asset Purchases,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 52, no. 3, (2012): 254-266.

  9. Emily Cadman, “Mark Carney Warns of Dangers of Growing Inequality,Financial Times May 28 (2014) and Andrew G Haldane, “Unfair Shares,” Executive Director, Financial Stability and member of the Financial Policy Committee, Bristol Festival of Ideas, 21 May (2014)

  10. See for instance Stephen D. Williamson, “Quantitative Easing: How Well Does This Tool Work?Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis August 18 (2017), available at and Dietrich Domanski, Michela Scatigna, and Anna Zabai, “Wealth Inequality and Monetary Policy,” BIS Quarterly Review March (2016): 45-64. On the different distributive effects of real estate and stock-price surges, see Moritz Kuhn, Moritz Schularick, and Ulrike Steins, “Income and Wealth Inequality in America, 1949-2016,” Journal of Political Economy 128, no. 9 (2020): 3469-519.

  11. Ben Bernanke, “Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 31 (2012).

  12. Sebastian Mallaby, The Man Who Knew: The Life and Times of Alan Greenspan (London: Bloomsbury, 2016), 49-52 and 208-214.12  In his hands, the wealth effect became a kind of funhouse mirror Keynesianism. As asset values rose, wealthy households would expand their consumption. By leveraging their existing assets, they could borrow (and spend) even more, and so on, in a regressive and financialized version of the multiplier effect. 

    Greenspan’s wager paid off in the late 1990s, when a bull market undoubtedly stimulated a surge in high-end consumer spending, and in the early 2000s, when rising home equity values had the same effect on homeowners. This wealth-driven consumption created jobs too, but crucially it did so without empowering workers. In sharp contrast to the high-pressure economy of the late 1960s and early 1970s, when the building trades unions were feared as the instigators of generalized wage inflation, the residential construction boom of the 2000s saw house prices rise steadily while construction wages declined.13Marc Doussard, Degraded Work: The Struggle at the Bottom of the Labor Market (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 2013), 144. For Greenspan’s earlier complaints about powerful building trades unions: Alan Greenspan, “The Escalation of Wages in Construction,” District Court Jurisdiction Over Unfair Labor Practice Cases Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Separation of Powers of the Committee on the Judiciary, United States Senate, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session on S. 3671, July 21, 22, 23 (Washington, DC: United States Congress, 1970), 247-277.

  13. Juan Montecino and Gerald Epstein, “Did Quantitative Easing Increase Income Inequality?” Institute for New Economic Thinking Working Paper Series No. 28, October (2015): 24.

  14. Domash and Summers predict “extremely rapid growth in nominal wages” in the year ahead. Alex Domash and Lawrence H. Summers, “How Tight are U.S. Labor Markets?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 29739, February (2022): 32. For a rebuttal of this view and a consideration of the supply side drivers of current consumer price inflation, see Servaas Storm, “Inflation in a Time of Corona and War,” INET Institute for New Economic Thinking June 6 (2022). Inspired by Lawrence Summers, journalists in Australia have greeted the election of the center-left Labor government led by Anthony Albanese with the prognosis that the country will soon see a return to the kind of wage-price spiral last seen under the left-wing Labor government of Gough Whitlam in the early 1970s. Matthew Knott, “‘Perfect Storm’: Is the Australian Economy Heading Back to the 1970s?Sydney Morning Herald June 18 (2022). For a more convincing analysis, which points out that recent rises to the minimum wage lag behind consumer price inflation, see Greg Jericho, “Workers and their Wages are the Collateral Damage of the War on Inflation,” Guardian (Australia) June 16 (2022).

  15. Richard D. Lyons, “Fears of H.E.W. Cuts Spur Protests at Inflation Parley,” New York Times September 20 (1974): 81.

  16. Michał Kalecki, “Political Aspects of Full Employment,” The Political Quarterly 14, no. 4 (1943), 322-330.

  17. An important exception here is James O’Connor who thought that the 1970s’ “fiscal crisis” of the capitalist state could be solved, in one scenario, by a transition to a full socialization of state fiscal powers. James O’Connor, The Fiscal Crisis of the State (New York, St. Martin’s Press, 1973).

  18. On Keynesianism as a form of Hegelianism, see Geoff Mann, In the Long Run We’re All Dead: Keynes, Political Economy, and Revolution (New York: Verso, 2017).

  19. For prominent Marxist critiques of MMT, see Doug Henwood, “Modern Monetary Theory Isn’t Helping,” Jacobin 21 February (2019), Paul Mattick, “Money Magic,” The Brooklyn Rail October (2020), and Michael Roberts, “Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique,” Class, Race and Corporate Power 7, no. 1 (2019). While these critics helpfully foreground the relationship between money and class conflict, they remain faithful to Marx’s nineteenth-century analysis of commodity money (in which money equals gold, and the value of gold is treated as if determined, like any other commodity, by the labor time required for its production). This fidelity ultimately blinds them to the possibilities—and complexities—of struggles around money and debt creation today, when money is created by states and by private banks. The attachment to commodity money is captured in Paul Mattick’s incredulous protest: “it just seems unlikely that money can be printed and handed out indefinitely without any problems.” Moreover, Marxist critiques of MMT often elide the difference between debt monetization in the service of wage inflation (the specter haunting the 1970s) and debt monetization in the service of asset-price inflation (the reality of QE). Thus, they misread QE as a technocratic implementation of MMT principles and condemn both for violating the laws of sound finance.

  20. Eric Blanc, Red State Revolt: The Teachers Strike Wave and Working-Class Politics (New York: Verso, 2019). The public sector strike upsurge is not confined to the United States. On the recent strike wave in the Australian public sector, which occurred despite a legislated wage cap, see Mihajla Gavin, “Public Sector Strikes are Back, With a Vengeance,” Sydney Morning Herald December 7 (2021). These strikes included public-school teachers, nurses and transport workers.

  21. Sam Gindin and Leo Panitch, The Making of Global Capitalism: The Political Economy of American Empire (New York: Verso, 2012), 141.

  22. Samir Sonti, “The Crisis of US Labor, Past and Present,” Socialist Register 122 (2022): 153-54 and Sarah Jaffe, “The Radical Organizing that Paved the Way for the LA Teachers’ Strike,” The Nation, 19 January (2019).


In one of her first statements as Treasury Secretary, Janet Yellen said that the United States faced “an economic crisis that has been building for fifty years.” The formulation is…

Read the full article


In early 2020, the “dash for cash” in the US Treasury market prompted the Fed to relaunch its dollar swap lines, which it eventually did in mid-March of that year.…

Read the full article


We live in the age of the central bank. The financial crisis of 2008 and the COVID-19 crash of 2020 have made visible the central role of the US Federal…

Read the full article